RT News

Sunday, February 13, 2011

US, China closer to trade war: Everything in Walmart and Home Depot comes from China

Thu Feb 10, 2011 8:35AM

The US dollar vs the Chinese Yuan

US lawmakers say they are pushing for a legislation that would punish China for allegedly manipulating its currency.


The draft bill, which is to be submitted on Thursday, is to address what the US senators describe as the unlawful practice of currency manipulation, according to the AP.

Both Republican and Democratic senators had informed US Treasury Secretary Timothy Geithner about the draft bill a month ago.

Relations between Beijing and Washington have been strained over the issues of currency and trade.

Washington accuses Beijing of manipulating the value of the Yuan to help boost Chinese exports.
Their bill, which could lead to counteract duties on Chinese exports, revives one that cleared the House of Representatives by a 348-79 vote in September but was stalled in the Senate.

China states that it will allow Yuan to gain value at a measured pace.
US Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke, however, voiced one of Washington's key complaints against China on Wednesday and claimed Beijing would be better off letting the Yuan appreciate by loosening its tie to the dollar.

"The Renminbi is undervalued," Bernanke told a hearing of the House of Representatives budget committee. Renminbi is the official term for the Yuan.

"It would be both in our interest and in the Chinese interest for them to raise the value of their currency. And it would help them with their inflation problem," he said.

Bernanke went on to openly fault Chinese financial policy makers and suggesting that they do not take China's interests into consideration.

"One of the things that's happening, which is a little surprising in a way, is that they have an inflation problem, and the way they are addressing it is not by raising their currency value, which would reduce the demand for their exports," added the US official.

"A better strategy would be to let domestic demand be what it is and let people enjoy higher standards of living," he claimed.

His comments represent a rare criticism of another central bank's policies by a central bank.

Beijing's third straight interest rate rise in four months was aimed at slowing down inflation in what some economists have described as an overheating economy growing at a 10-percent rate annually.

===

US says sanctions possible in China copyright spat
25 Mar 2011 22:40

Source: reuters // Reuters


* China says complies with most measures at issue

* U.S. still "troubled" by lack of progress

* U.S. says in preliminary talks on possible sanctions (Updates with more detail of US comment)

By Andrew Callus

GENEVA, March 25 (Reuters) - China said on Friday it complied with "most measures at issue" in an international trade ruling made against its restrictions on copyright-intensive goods such as films, books and music.

But the United States, which filed the case against China years ago, took a dimmer view of Beijing's action to date and said the two sides had begun discussions of how to proceed if Washington decides to pursue a request to impose sanctions.

China's statement made in Geneva at the World Trade Organization (WTO) headquarters came six days after a deadline to comply with the WTO ruling elapsed.

The United States says China's restrictions on goods such as books, newspapers, films, DVDs and music create demand for pirated goods. China lost a WTO appellate body ruling in December 2009 and agreed with the United States that it would implement the decision by March 19, 2011.

China said the dispute was "embodied with more complexity and sensitivity than other disputes."

"China made tremendous efforts to implement the DSB's rulings and recommendations and so far has completed amendments to most measures at issue," it said, referring to the WTO's dispute settlement body.

But the United States said China still had a ways to go to comply with the ruling.

"The United States is troubled by the lack of any apparent progress by China in bringing its measures relating to films for theatrical release into compliance with the DSB (dispute settlement body) recommendations and rulings," the United States said in its statement.

"The United States also has significant concerns about the incomplete progress relative to China's measures relating to audio visual home entertainment products, reading materials and sound recordings," it added.

U.S. officials informed the WTO membership that it has begun discussions with China on the possibility of the United States requesting WTO permission to impose sanctions in the dispute, known in WTO jargon as "suspending concessions."

"The United States and China are in discussions regarding how to handle any eventual request for a compliance proceeding ... and any eventual request for authorization to suspend concessions," the United States said.

"The United States hopes to report progress in those discussions in the coming days," it said.

(Additional reporting by Doug Palmer in Washington; editing by Philip Barbara)

======


Will China Slow Down by 2015?
Posted by Stuart Staniford at 5:59 AM


A new paper was released by the prestigious National Bureau of Economic Research a few days ago. The authors are well known and work at distinguished institutions: first author Barry Eichengreen is a widely cited expert at UC Berkeley, Donghyun Park is at the Asian Development Bank, and Kwanho Shin is at the Korea University in Seoul. The paper was approvingly cited by savvy bloggers like Kevin Drum and Ryan Avent at the Economist's Free Exchange blog. Here's what the abstract says:



However, I downloaded the paper (paying my $5 in the process) and read it. And I think the data analysis is deeply flawed and the paper's conclusions are wrong. Let me try to explain what the paper is saying and why you should pay attention to me, instead of to its prestigious authors.

First, let me be clear that I completely agree with the basic conceptual worldview of the paper:




I don't have any problem with this characterization for why late developing countries can grow faster than already industrialized countries, or that this process must end. I agree that countries like Japan, Korea, and Taiwan can be considered to have gone through this process, and are worth studying as analogies. I agree that the question of when this kind of slowdown will come to China is an extremely important question. My problem is with the way they go about trying to answer it.

What they do is to go through at database of country level GDP data back to 1950 (the Penn World Tables) and look for situations like the following:

Countries that had a growth over 3.5% for an interval of seven years
Followed by an interval of growth at least two percentage points lower for the following seven years.
Which ended up with a GDP/capita of at least $10k/yr (in 2005 prices).
This sounds superficially reasonable. The sample they end up with is listed in their Table 1, and to give you a flavor of it, here's the start of the table (which goes on for another five pages):




Then they look at the income levels that each country was at when the growth slowdown happened. They throw out the oil exporters as being driven by different dynamics (as I will also). Then they construct the following histogram:




This is where the $17,000 average level in the table comes from (they don't label the x-axis, but it's per-capita GDP). And once they have that, it's straightforward to see that China will cross that level in about five years, the most striking claim in the abstract.

To see the problems with what they are doing, let's start by taking all the countries in their Table 1 sample and plotting their real GDP/capita over the entire 1950-2009 interval that the Penn World Tables presently have:




Here I have added China to their sample as the heavy red line at the bottom (that's the one where we are trying to figure out what will happen). I have also made the US a heavy black line to be easier to see. Note that the US is in their sample, which should immediately give you pause, because I think we should view the US as essentially having been at or near the current technological productivity frontier at all times since the second world war. I have also marked with a green horizontal dotted line the approximate $17k/capita level that they say is the average of the growth slowdowns. A red vertical line is at 2015, where they say China is probably going to experience the same thing.

To illustrate some of the problems with their sample and procedure, I have removed all but three of the cases (also leaving in the US and China for comparison). I am also marking with a purple circle some of their growth slowdowns. These examples are not exhaustive of the issues with the sample, but are intended to illustrate a variety of classes of problems:





First, let's talk about Denmark (the blue line). Eichengreen et al have a slowdown in Denmark in the years 1964/1965 in their sample. Now, I'm not disputing that growth slowed down, but let me point out that this was a full fifty years before 2015. Are we really sure that GDP/capita in Denmark in 1965 tells us a lot about GDP/capita in China fifty years later? In particular, note that US GDP/capita has increased by a factor of close to three over the intervening time: there have been enormous increases in productivity in 50 years, and this means that a GDP/capita of $13,944 (in 2005 dollars) in Denmark in 1965 means something completely different than $13,944 (still in 2005 dollars) would mean today. The same income level is a lot further from the technological productivity frontier today than it was then. Nonetheless, they are including that data point in their sample.

Furthermore, Denmark, like another of my problematic cases, the Netherlands, is really not a very persuasive story of being a fast growing developing country that hit the limits of their ability to play catchup with the advanced countries. Places like the Netherlands were already advanced countries in 1950, and the ratio of their GDP/capita to that of the US is relatively constant over time. The Netherlands gets into the sample because of a growth slowdown in the early 1970s - three years are in the table in 1970, 1973, and 1974. I have circled 1973/1974 as the most visible setback in the GDP/capita line. But again - this is not a fast developing country hitting the limits of its ability to over-invest in catchup - there was an oil shock in 1973! This is a story, like most of the advanced countries, of an oil-shock inducing a recession and a slowdown in growth. Again, this can't possibly tell us much about the income level when China will hit the limits of catch-up.

Finally, Uruguay (the sort of peachy colored line), which is listed for a slowdown in the mid 1990s. The problem here is that Uruguay is a completely unpersuasive analogy for what is happening in China. Uruguay starts and ends the sample as a lower-middle income country, and has never had an extended period of growth anything like the 10%/year level we've seen in China in recent years.

To try to get a better grip on the situation, I did two things. Firstly, to formalize the instinct that the US has been at/near the productivity frontier at most times, I expressed every country's GDP/capita as a fraction of the US value in the same year. Then I started kicking countries out of the sample, unless they met the following criteria: they started out the sample clearly less productive than the US (I took less than 60% as my threshold), and ended up significantly more productive, relative to the US, than they had started out. Ie, we want countries where it's somewhat plausible that there's a story of underdevelopment, period of rapid catchup, followed by slowing growth once the country is a fully developed country with modern capital infrastructure and levels of productivity.

That gives me this (much smaller) sample:





You can see that the sample consists of two main classes:

mostly central and southern European countries that were somewhat more rural than the US or northern European economies in 1950, grew faster than the US in the 1950s and 1960s, and then slowed down to a similar pace of growth
Asian countries that grew very fast somewhat later, but have slowed since (places like Japan, Korea, Taiwan, etc).
I think this is much better implementation of the core idea behind the Eichengreen et al paper. However, you can see that this recasting really changes the answer. There is a big range of where these countries experience a slowdown, but broadly speaking it's in the range of 50-100% of US GDP/capita. The lower end of the spectrum is occupied by places like Portugal and Greece, where, how to say it, people place a higher value on quality of life, and less value on maximizing their economic production. The upper ranges find places like Japan and Singapore, where the occupants are driven and ambitious. I think we can all see that China in the last couple of decades has been about the most driven and ambitious society the modern world has seen.

In that last figure, I also show (red dotted line) what happens if you extrapolate China's growth relative to the US for the next decade at the same pace as over the last ten years (a shade over 9%/year). You can see that by 2020, they are just getting to the lower end of the range. They will not be very close to it in 2015, contrary to what Eichengreen et al are saying.

As for the rest of the Eichengreen paper -- a bunch of regression experiments on their sample to find out what else influences the level of growth slowdown -- I won't deal with it in detail. If the sample is deeply flawed and the dependent variable is completely inappropriate, who knows what they'll find once they start plugging lots of things into the statistical black boxes, but it's not likely to be much in the way of insight.

Finally, I want to stress one thing: I am not saying China will definitely continue growing at breakneck pace for another decade plus. I think there are profound risks to that possibility: it seems very likely that so much growth in that large a country will trigger more big resource price shocks, which will slow China as well as everyone else. Plus, we are already at the point where it seems like it's only a slight humorous exaggeration to say that everything in Walmart and Home Depot comes from China, and it's not at all clear that they can continue to increase their exports at the recent pace for another 10-15 years. Furthermore, there are obviously large internal political risks in China's authoritarian system. What I'm saying instead is this: if they slowdown before something like 2025, it's very unlikely to be due to the fact that they've reached close enough to developed country productivity levels that they can no longer do fast catch-up growth. The reason will be different.
Posted by Stuart Staniford at 5:59 AM

===========


Red, rich and rising
Rise of red capitalists need not be bad for China
27 September 2011 | By Wei Gu

China’s Communist Party is getting more inclusive towards capitalists, and that may be no bad thing. The Party may elevate China’s richest man, industrialist Liang Wengen, to its elite central committee, according to a report in Time Weekly magazine. There are risks when money and power get too close. But China has much to gain from giving higher status to the private sector, and nurturing entrepreneurship.

Embracing the low-profile Liang, whose wealth was measured at $9.3 billion by the Forbes Rich List in September, is symbolic. The party’s 200-odd-member central committee is made up mostly of politicians and heads of state-owned companies. Yet private companies are growing faster than the rest of the economy, and now make up 50 percent of China’s GDP, according to the Federation of Industry and Commerce, in spite of policies that favour of SOEs and foreign enterprises.

It’s wise to reassure the wealthy. Many of China’s successful entrepreneurs are already taking their talents and capital elsewhere. About 27 percent of Chinese with investable assets above $1.5 million have already changed nationality, according to a survey by China Merchants Bank. The number of Chinese people emigrating to the United States through the investment channel has risen at an average of 73 percent a year for the past five years.

Entrepreneurs have much to teach China’s leaders. The country has been run for a decade by engineers, who were experts at building things. Businessmen tend to pay more attention to earning a return on capital, and can help promote a higher-quality of growth. They also have more experience of driving efficiency, and create more jobs than the capital-intensive SOEs.=State Owned Enterprise

Crony capitalism is the biggest risk. Some will worry that Liang is just trading wealth for power, though he can help allay those concerns by arguing powerfully and publicly for better treatment of the private sector. But Liang’s promotion at least makes the link between big business more transparent. If it is handled right, promoting the red capitalists may bring positive changes for China’s economy.

-
Sany Heavy Industry Chairman Liang Wengen may become a deputy governor of Hunan province, where the company is based, according to Chinese magazine Time Weekly. He is also tapped to join the Communist Party’s elite 200-member central committee in 2012, it said.

Liang was named as China’s richest man in the Forbes Rich List, released on Sept. 8.

Sany, China’s largest construction machinery maker, on Sept. 22 postponed a Hong Kong initial public offering of up to $3.3 billion, due to tumbling global markets.
=========

No comments: